|
Glasgow Green - Glasgow Museums Resource Centre via Art UK |
On 8 February, the Scottish Parliament's Local Government and Communities Committee issued a Call for Evidence on Common Good Property and Funds. The following was my submission.
Executive
summary
*The
category of inalienable common good should be abolished – because it’s absurdly illogical that some
public parks have an additional layer of protection which others don’t just
because of accidents of history. But note that this abolition wouldn’t change a
property’s status as common good - it would just mean it was no longer
necessary to get sanction from the courts for sale/change of use because there
are alternative, more democratic, controls in place. (See 5.1 to 5.5 below)
*Enacting a statutory definition of common good
(CG) will not remove the legal obscurities associated with CG. The only thing
that can do that is a definitive register of common good (i.e. a
register such that, if a property isn’t in it, it isn’t CG, and vice versa,
“end of”). This is to avoid in future local authorities having projects
ambushed by dubious claims of CG (as with Portobello and Barrhead Schools). (See
2.1 to 2.5).
*Unless one already exists and is observed
universally, a rule that maintenance of common good assets should always be
the first charge on the revenue surplus of CG funds is required. (See 3.3)
General points – history and different categories of common good
0.1 I’ll come shortly to the five questions the
Committee wanted to see addressed in evidence but first make a couple of
general points. First – and I’m sure the Committee will get bored hearing this
– but it’s indispensably necessary to understand the historical
background to common good: you’ve got to know how we got here in order to
decide where we go from here. I’ve included a historical sketch as an appendix
but the key facts to take from it are these: in the pre-industrial era (before
the 19th century), its common good was the totality of a burgh’s assets
and funding sources: its endowment, in other words, to provide the services
(minimal by today's standards) then offered by local government. During the
industrial revolution, the assets of burghs grew massively through acquisition
under new statutory powers granted to meet the challenges of urbanisation and
population growth (education, sanitation, housing etc.) and this all came to be
paid for by taxation (rates) rather than from the burgh’s own endowment as
hitherto. In consequence, CG became overshadowed by burghs’ new statutory
assets and resources and, relatively speaking, dwindled to something of a
historical legacy. But the history should not obscure the fact that common good
is simply assets of a local authority: it no more (or less) belongs to “the
people” than any other LA asset such as a school, swimming pool, care home etc. or, indeed, the
money in the Council's bank account. Statements implying common good is some
sort of surviving relic of an aboriginal communal past (which somehow came to
be associated with towns) are the product of misunderstanding - for which the
very words "common" and "good" may be partly responsible -
coupled, perhaps, with a bit of wishful thinking on the part of their authors.
It may help to a proper understanding of the subject to recall that many
institutions with long histories (e.g. universities) have endowments which are
of less significance now than formerly as their source of funding. Scottish
burghs' endowments just happen to have a special name: common good.
0.2 Second, it’s essential to distinguish two
types of common good asset. The first is the revenue producing assets of common
good funds. These are portfolios of investments much like private trust or
pension funds: they are the legacy of burghs’ original endowments from the
pre-industrial era. CG funds tend to include a large percentage of real estate
(e.g. shops let to generate rent) but also include other investments such as
bonds, stocks and shares etc., these being commonly managed by professional
fund managers. LAs are at liberty to dispose of all these assets – of whatever
nature – without restriction in the course of managing their CG funds to
maintain the capital and maximise revenue returns.
0.3 Today, when their activities are mostly
funded by taxation, local authorities commonly use the annual revenue surplus
of CG funds to fund local “good causes” like a sort of local lottery fund (some
CG funds
are even registered charities). But LAs are not obliged to do this and
would be perfectly entitled to spend the money on something more prosaic like a
new link road or social care facility. The only legal requirement is that, in
administering a CG fund, the LA must “have regard to the interests of” the
burgh the fund belonged to before 1975.
Thus, Highland Council, for example, could apply the revenue surplus of the
Inverness CG fund to a good cause local to, or a new care facility in,
Inverness but not Fort William. And HC could probably not hand over the revenue
surplus of the Inverness CG fund to its (HC’s) general education budget
because that would be unlikely to be having sufficient “regard to the interests
of” Inverness as opposed to the rest of Highland as a whole.
0.4 The second type of CG is called inalienable
common good. Always corporeal property, it’s usually land and buildings but
can include moveables (chattels), typically civic regalia or art. (From hereon,
I’m going to assume inalienable CG is land or buildings.) These are the legacy
today of properties used in the management of the burgh and the provision of
the (relatively minimalist) services of yesteryear to the inhabitants:
tolbooths, gaols, churches etc. Also included are the public open spaces (of
which, in former times, recreational use was often subsidiary to some historic
function such as bleaching green, market stance or grazing for the burghers’
animals) which are the most high profile facet of common good today: Glasgow
Green and Edinburgh’s Meadows are both inalienable CG (although it’s worth
emphasising here that not every urban public park is CG). Note that, far from
being revenue generating assets, inalienable CG is almost invariably a liability
to LAs as requiring running costs and maintenance etc.
0.5 This type of CG was called inalienable
because, having been made available for use by the public, the burgh council
couldn’t deprive the public of it by disposal (or change of use) as it could
with land held merely as an investment in the CG fund. Simply banning disposal
was the solution of an earlier, pre-industrial era when there were fewer
democratic controls. Nowadays, however, “inalienable” is something of a
misnomer: LA’s can dispose of inalienable CG if it has ceased to be used by the
public. And even when still in use, the courts can authorise disposal or change
of use of inalienable CG on application by the LA.
Authorisation will usually be granted when a credible scheme is presented, typically
involving provision of a suitable alternative facility.
|
Kirkcaldy, 1840 |
The five
questions
1. Are the common law
rules which define common good property adequate?
1.1 It may not
be contained in a statute but the legal definition of common good (assets of CG
funds and inalienable) is admirably succinct: “all property of a burgh not
acquired under statutory powers or held under special trusts”. The problem lies in determining whether any
particular piece of LA owned land or buildings falls within the definition in
the commonly occurring case that its title deeds give no clue. An investigation
into the circumstances of its acquisition becomes necessary, typically
involving consulting burgh archives, which may not be conclusive. The legal
definitions of inalienable common good (i.e. the rules which distinguish
it from the freely disposable assets of CG funds) are less succinct and more
difficult to apply. There are clear cut cases at either end of the spectrum –
the let garage which is manifestly just held by an LA as an investment at one
end and Glasgow Green at the other – but there can be shades of grey in
between.
1.2 These
difficulties in applying the law cause LAs two problems. First, an LA may not
know if, after having sold a property, it will be able to apply the proceeds to
the use it intends or whether, if the assets turns out to be CG, the proceeds
will, in effect, be hypothecated to use in the burgh the relevant CG fund
belonged to by application of the “have regard to” rule (para. 0.3). Second, and
far more serious, an LA may not know if it can sell a property at all (or
change its use) in case it turns out to be inalienable CG and the courts refuse
to sanction the sale (or change).
1.3 As a
lawyer (retired), I can’t emphasise strongly enough that merely codifying the
common law rules in statute won’t make these uncertainties go away. No matter
how carefully worded any restatement were, it couldn’t cover every case with
certainty and grey areas would remain. (This is a very commonly occurring legal
syndrome, BTW, not by any means confined to common good: there would be little
need for lawyers and courts if it were otherwise!) The only way to make
these problems go away is to have a definitive register of CG. (See Q2
below).
2. Do you think the record
keeping of common good property and assets held by local authorities could be
improved?
2.1 Record
keeping should improve when s.102 of the Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act
2015 requiring LAs to maintain registers of CG property comes into force but
these registers will suffer from a critical defect: they won’t be legally
definitive. What that means is that the fact that a property is not
included in the register is not conclusive that it’s not CG (and vice
versa). In other words, nobody will be able to consult the registers and get a
definite answer whether a particular piece of property is or is not CG. The
second main defect of the s.102 registers is that they won’t distinguish
between the freely disposable assets held in common good funds and inalienable
CG.
2.2 Therefore,
I would suggest s.102 be amended before it comes into force so that the
registers become (i) legally conclusive as to CG status; and (ii) identify
which properties are inalienable with the registers also being conclusive as to
that. I’d also suggest that, so far as they relate to CG land and buildings,
the registers be integrated with the Land Register in order to advance the LR’s
role as a “one stop shop” for all land rights and responsibilities. Definitive
registers of CG integrated with the Land Register was an aspiration of the Land
Reform Review Group
2.3 Whether
the s.102 registers should be definitive was touched on in the policy
memorandum for the CE Bill:-
Given the complexity of the subject, there is a high
risk that [making the registers definitive] might not cover
all existing assets which are considered to be common good, and might cover
things which are currently excluded. Rather, the intention is to provide an
opportunity for community councils, other community bodies and individuals to
see what the local authority considers to be common good property, and to
highlight any items they believe should be included (or omitted). It is not
intended that local authorities will be expected to legally verify the status
of every item on the register or proposed during the consultation; this will
normally only be necessary if there is significant dispute.
2.4 But I
think the Scotgov answered its own concern there: the registers would be
prepared by LAs in draft according to their understanding of their CG holdings.
Then they would be put out for consultation so that community councils, bodies
and individuals could propose amendments. Any disputed cases could be
determined by the Lands Tribunal. After a long enough period for amendments to
come forward and be determined – say 10 years? (cf. timescales for completion
of the Land Register) – the registers would become final and there would be
closure. It would be not unlike the process of developing a local plan in the
planning context.
2.5 If
definitive registers of all CG are nevertheless considered to be
impractical, then give consideration to the definitive registers applying only
to inalienable CG. The reasoning there is two-fold: first, inalienable
CG ought to be easier to identify (the public parks, the old townhouses etc.).
Second, inalienability has the potential to block a transaction altogether so
it's more important that the properties affected are definitively identified as
such. With "alienable" LA assets, on the other hand, they can still
be sold even if they later turn out to have been CG: the sale does not prevent
the proceeds being later credited to the CG fund if the result of a subsequent
investigation so requires.
2.6 Another
point on the s.102 registers as currently proposed (it’s a prime example of
inattention to the distinctions between the freely disposable assets of CG
funds and inalienable CG): a literal reading of s.102 means that even the
incorporeal assets of CG funds (their stocks, shares and other “paper”
investments) have to be included in the registers. Do they also have to be
“de-registered” each time a stock is sold in the ordinary course of fund
management? This is an excessive burden on the funds. A lighter touch
disclosure of investment policies would be appropriate (see 3.2 below) and
s.102 should be amended to apply only to corporeal property (chattels,
land and buildings).
2.7
Recognising that less than 1% by value of LA property is common good,
a helpful interim measure pending the definitive registers becoming final (or
permanent measure in the event the concept of definitive registers doesn't find
favour) would be a statutory presumption that LA property is not CG. Reflecting
the history (see Appendix), this could apply only to property acquired after,
say, 1850.
3. Is there enough
openness and direct engagement with local communities on common good property
and funds and the use to which common good property and assets are put?
3.1 To an
extent, this question appears to prejudge s.104 of the Community Empowerment
(Scotland) Act 2015 mandating consultation with local communities before
disposal or change of use of CG assets before it has been brought into force. I
suspect a ministerial response to this question would be to allow s.104 to bed
in before any further action is proposed. I come back to s.104 in para. 5.6
below.
3.2. Aside from
disposal and change of use, there could be a case for requiring LAs to produce
- in accordance with ministerial guidelines to achieve consistency and after
public consultation - medium/long term forward
plans for their common good funds (portfolios of income generating
investments, not public parks etc.) covering investment strategies and policies
for spending revenue surpluses. S.104 would need to be amended to cover this.
3.3 There’s
another point I’d like to raise here, not as “evidence” from my own knowledge
but rather a question which, if I were a member of the committee, I would want
to ask of those qualified to answer it: I gather many CG funds rent assets
(typically buildings) to their own LAs. That’s fair as the residents of the rest
of the LA area are paying the burgh the CG fund “belongs to” a rent for the use
of “their” (the burgh’s) property. But what about the converse – does it ever
happen that unremunerative CG assets (typically inalienable CG such as public
parks) are run at the expense of the LA’s general fund as opposed to the CG
fund? If so, is this legal? I believe there used to be a maxim that the common
good could subsidise the rates but not the other way round. I presume that must
since have been varied by statute or else the point would surely have come up
at audit before now but even if it’s legal, is it fair? If the general
fund is paying for it, should the asset not be the “property” of all the
residents of the LA area, not just the former burgh in which it happens to be
situated? In the course of preparing this evidence, I did a not very scientific
survey of how about two thirds of LAs had accounted for CG in their annual
accounts for 2015-16. In one or two, it appeared that the general fund (“the
rates”) running CG assets might be being effected by “finance leases” by the CG
fund to the general fund at a peppercorn rent but in only one of the sets of accounts
I looked at – Highland Council – did I see a clear statement of how I believe
it ought to work:
All funds are held for the
benefit of the residents of those former burghs and must be used in the
first instance to maintain the assets of the Common Good. Thereafter funds can
be used for purposes which are in the interests of the community for which
the Common Good Fund was established. [Emphasis added.]
I wonder if that doesn’t need to be made a statutory
requirement for all LAs? If it doesn’t, then, because the question was
even asked, it perhaps resolves into one of transparency of accounting and
reporting as to which see Q4 below.
4. Are details of common
good property and assets and income generated by their sale clear and
transparent?
4.1 As I
understand it, LAs are required to prepare accounts in accordance with the
CIPFA/LASAAC Code of Practice for Local Authority Accounting which requires
that CG funds be accounted for separately and in accordance with certain
standards. No doubt LAs comply with this but these accounts are not easy for
lay people to interpret. I would therefore suggest that more user-friendly
“Ladybird Book” accounts be required (as well as, not instead of, the
“official” accounts). These could perhaps be included in a sort of annual
report and be in accordance with ministerial guidelines to ensure consistency
of format across all LAs to include a simple statement of money in (where it
came from), money out (where it went) and how any surplus was disbursed or
retained. There would also be a statement of the composition of the capital
(land & buildings, categories of other investments, cash, loans etc.) and
capital transactions (gains/losses on disposal and “paper” transactions such as
revaluation and depreciation).
5. Any other issues
relating to common good property, assets and funds which you wish to bring to
the attention of the Committee?
5.1 The category of inalienable common
good should be abolished.
5.2 I can’t emphasise strongly enough that I’m
not suggesting common good be abolished altogether, only that inalienable CG
assets be placed on the same footing as the disposable assets of CG funds. They
will still form part of the common good and all the change would mean in
practice is that an LA would no longer have to obtain permission from the
courts to dispose (or change the use) of an asset presently classified as
inalienable CG. But the proceeds of sale would still go into the CG fund for
reinvestment or disbursement according to the fund's set priorities.
5.3 Why would one propose this dilution of
protection for CG assets? Well, for a start, it’s highly illogical that some,
but not all, public parks (to use the classic example of inalienable CG) have
the extra layer of protection by the courts. Your average person in the street
is likely to find it very hard to understand why accidents of history can lead
to a much needed new school being blocked on one public park while another identical
one across the road can be sold off for executive housing just because it
doesn’t happen to be CG. It’s an absurdity which brings common good – indeed
Scots law as a whole – into disrepute. Protections for inalienable CG were
loosened without a murmur of dissent in the wake of the Portobello Park fiasco
so it may be advisable to be proactively radical now before another Portobello
type situation comes along and puts common good on the defensive again.
5.4 Secondly, are the unelected judiciary the
best people to decide the fate of CG properties? Should the matter not be
decided at the bar of public opinion? The inalienability rule dates from
centuries ago and was the law of the time’s blunt edged sword to protect the
public’s access to facilities provided for their use in an era when the pace of
change was slower than today and before there were democratic fora to debate
such matters. The ability of the courts to authorise disposal was introduced in
1947
in an era when there wasn’t the consultation of the public by LAs there is
today. But now we have s.104 of the Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015 (not
in force yet) statutorily requiring publication and local consultation before disposal
or change of use of CG and LAs to have regard to views made known, do we really
need court sanction as well?
5.5 If there’s no appetite to abolish
inalienability, then at least the inconsistency of treatment ought to be
removed by requiring court sanction for the disposal or change of use of all
(i.e. not just CG) LA property made available for public use (i.e. schools,
parks, libraries etc. but not LA offices, depots etc.). Or only s.104
consultation before disposal/change of use of any publicly used LA
asset, not just CG.
5.6 Finally, even if none of these suggestions
commends itself, s.104 still needs to be amended before it comes in to force
such that it only applies to inalienable CG and not the freely disposable
assets held in CG funds. You can’t manage a fund properly if public
consultation is required before every disposal: an urgent reactions to sudden
market changes may be required. (S.104 consultation should be retained for the
sorts of medium/long term forward plan for CG funds I suggested in para. 3.2
above, however.)
Appendix – Historical
sketch
[Note - this was drawn from a blog post I wrote in September 2014 about Cowan Park in Barrhead (here) so anyone who read that doesn't need to read this.]
Medieval Origins
Nowadays, government finances its expenditure by tax.
But in the Middle Ages, the authorities were supposed to “live off their own”, that
is finance their official functions from their own property. Burghs were a sort
of medieval equivalent of today’s Enterprise Zones or Freeports. When they were
established in Scotland from the 12th century onwards by the Crown (“royal
burgh”) or a lay or ecclesiastical magnate (“burgh of barony”), burghs
were given by their patron an endowment, the income from which was meant to
finance their activities.
Today, if you wanted to
endow something, you’d give a sum of money to fund managers to invest in a portfolio
of stocks, shares and other investments. But in the Middle Ages, the stock
market didn’t exist and the only thing which yielded an annual return was land
in the shape of the rent paid by its tenants. Thus, the endowment of medieval
burghs was land and this land is a burgh’s “common good”. The rent the
common good land yielded funded the services the town provided
although, in a pre-industrial era, these were pretty minimalist and dated by
today’s standards: they did not, for example, include housing. Many burghs
provided a school although they were not obliged to and not all did: many
considered provision of a burgh kirk of greater importance. Beyond that, the
services provided often amounted to little more than a bit of rudimentary
street sweeping if there was anything left over after repairing the mercat
cross and the tolbooth.
There was a sub-set of
common good: property used by the town or its citizens. These included things
like the tolbooth (town hall & gaol) and such medieval arcana as public
bleaching greens and market stances. These were inalienable in the sense that
the magistrates couldn’t sell them on a whim and so deprive the citizens of
their use. But the rest of the common good – the majority of it which was just
the assets in the portfolio of the burgh’s endowment, so to speak – was freely
alienable by the council. Thus, if Blackburgh Town Council
happened to own the lands of Whitecraigs, it could sell them and invest the
proceeds in the lands of Greenriggs instead just as the trustees of a modern
endowment might sell shares in Company A to reinvest in Company B. But it
couldn’t sell the market stance if it happened to become marketable.
Another feature of burgh
life in times gone by was the “special trust”. Nowadays, if you want to donate
money for a purpose not catered for by one of the numerous established
charities, you would nominate your own trustees. But in previous centuries
(when there were few charities as we now understand them), donors tended to
nominate their local burgh council as trustee: such trusts were often known as
“mortifications”. Again, the principal investment was usually land but
the magistrates had to apply the rents to the particular local purpose directed
by the donor – typically educational or care of orphans or the elderly or else
maintenance of a particular facility such as a ferry or bridge.
Industrial Revolution - statutory powers and rates
The arrangements described
above were barely adequate in the pre-industrial era but cracked fatally under
the strain of the onset of the Industrial Revolution in the second half of the
18th century. The meagre resources of the common good supplemented by trusts
(i.e. charity) proved totally inadequate to finance the new challenges faced by
rapidly growing towns such as improved water supplies, sanitation, street
lighting etc.
At first, individual burghs responded by obtaining private Acts of
Parliament authorising specific projects paid for by levying a tax – a “rate” –
on the citizens. There was also the problem of towns which were not burghs
(royal or baronial) and so had no resources to fund improvements at all: some
of these (Airdrie is an example) responded by seeking an Act to incorporate
themselves as a burgh, conferring statutory powers of management and to levy
rates to pay for them. These statutory developments continued and grew until
they reached a culmination in the Burgh Police (Scotland) Act 1892 (the word
“police” used there in its original sense of civic government generally rather
than just law enforcement). This Act gave the local sheriff power to declare
any town with a population over 700 a burgh and gave all burghs – existing and new,
royal or baronial – a vast range of powers of management ranging down to
minutiae such as bathing machines, shoeblack stands and abuse of steam whistles
and trumpets. In a parallel development, general Acts of Parliament were passed
on subjects of more general import – e.g. education and housing – giving burghs
the power – and, increasingly in the 20th century, the duty – to provide
these services. And all of this legislation was underpinned by powers to pay
for everything through rates imposed on the citizens.
So far as burghs’ property portfolios were
concerned, therefore, by the 20th century, the common good (and land
held by trusts administered by burghs) had become a historical legacy dwarfed
by the vast extent of the schools, reservoirs, sewage works, council house
estates etc. etc. acquired as a result of these statutory developments. Hence
the generally recognised legal definition of common good in a dictum by Lord Wark in the 1944 Court of
Session case Magistrates of Banff v Ruthin Castle Ltd: “all property of a [burgh] not acquired under statutory
powers or held under special trusts forms part of the common good”.
Footnotes